The WaPo discovers unintended consequences

Posted by Marc Hodak on August 30, 2010 under Unintended consequences | Be the First to Comment

At least the guy at the head of the organization does:

The U.S. Education Department this summer proposed regulations that would tie access to federal aid programs to graduates’ success in paying off loans.

“They aimed at the bad actors and they wound up scoring a direct hit on schools that service low-income students,” Mr. Graham said in an interview. “That cannot be what the Obama administration wants.”

Is it possible that the Obama administration doesn’t understand all the consequences of its proposals?

Practical definition: Hubris

Posted by Marc Hodak on under Collectivist instinct, Patterns without intention | Be the First to Comment

From a speech today:

“Every single day, I’m pushing this economy forward, repairing the damage that’s been done to the middle class over the past decade and promoting the growth we need to get out people back to work,” Obama said.

No statement better reflects the fatal conceit.

Contrast with this, from one of Hayek’s discliples:

There were two great triumphs, two things that I’m proudest of.  One is the economic recovery, in which the people of America created — and filled — 19 million new jobs.

Good god, what a difference.

Research on employee rankings

Posted by Marc Hodak on August 18, 2010 under Revealed preference, Unintended consequences | Be the First to Comment

Theory:  Ranking employees, and letting them know where they rank, inspires a competition to improve one’s performance, or to continue to excel.

Experimental result: Not

[Professor] Barankay [of Wharton] randomly divided workers into two groups — a control group receiving no ranking and a treatment group receiving feedback with a ranking. He then sent an e-mail to all of the workers inviting them to return to do more assignments. The content of all the e-mails was the same, except that individuals in the treatment group found out how they ranked in terms of their answers’ accuracy. The aim was to determine whether giving people feedback affected their desire to do more work, as well as the quantity and quality of their work. Of the workers in the control group, 66% came back for more work, compared with 42% in the treatment group. The members of the treatment group who returned were also 22% less productive than the control group.

Prof. Barankay also offered workers either a job where they would be ranked or one where they wouldn’t be.

[T]he job without the feedback attracted more workers — 254, compared with 76 for the job with feedback.

“This was a surprising outcome, but it speaks to the paradigm of revealed preferences,” he notes. “Economists are usually very skeptical about what people say they will do. We focus on what people actually choose to do. Their choices convey information about what they care about. In this case, it seems that people would rather not know how they rank compared to others, even though when we surveyed these workers after the experiment, 74% said they wanted feedback about their rank.”

So, people generally don’t like to be ranked against their peers, even though they say they do, and rankings appear to encourage the high performers to slack off and the poor performers to give up.  Contrary to theory, it also encourages high performers to leave and poor performers to stay.  High performers are given the confidence to go out and find new challenges, while poor performers appear to get demoralized, and may have fewer options besides.

This research stands in contrast to research on tournaments, which appear to motivate more productive behavior.  Thus, the research indicates that it depends on how the feedback and reward mechanisms interact.  Competition can breed excellence, and competition includes comparisons and consequences.  But comparison alone can breed complacency or demoralization.

“The central question…”

Posted by Marc Hodak on August 16, 2010 under Invisible trade-offs, Unintended consequences | Be the First to Comment

David Leonhardt suggests that “The part of the [financial services overhaul] law that will directly affect the most people will be the new Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, which has already been the subject of heated debate. And the central question facing the bureau will be how to distinguish between corporate malfeasance and consumer frailty.”

This is how I would expect a NYT columnist to see the central question, i.e., as a distinction that experts must make about when a financial instrument or transaction goes from being merely too hard for someone understand to being deceptive.  While many pundits and readers no doubt share this view of “the central question,” I think it distracts us from far more interesting questions:

Read more of this article »

Your customer wants to see how much you make

Posted by Marc Hodak on August 10, 2010 under Government service, Stupid laws | Read the First Comment

Higher disclosure standards for executives

New, higher disclosure standards for executives

Imagine that one of your large customers, say you’re a supplier to Target or Whole Foods, wants you to disclose how much you and your senior officers make?  You’re a private company, you may not even tell your kids or siblings how much you make, but these strangers want to know, and they want to place that information on the Internet.  How would you feel about that?

Well, that is exactly what the Federal government is requiring of its contractors and sub-contractors via rules in the Federal Acquisition Regulation (FAR).

HP scandal helps to answer “What is a CEO worth?”

Posted by Marc Hodak on August 9, 2010 under Executive compensation, Revealed preference, Scandal | Be the First to Comment

CEO pay is generally discussed and debated from the point of view of more typical kinds of employees, from minimum wage teens to well-salaried executives, who work for what seem like arbitrary sums offered by frugal or venal owners, or their sometimes clueless representatives on the board.  At this level of the discussion, one loses a key distinction about pay in a market economy, i.e., that one should be paid about what they’re worth.  So, a relevant question in this debate that is never asked:  What is a CEO worth?

Mark Hurd’s sudden, surprise resignation at HP offers a rare hint to the answer; in after-hours trading shortly after the announcement of his dismissal, HP’s stock declined by over 8 percent.

Ladies and gentlemen, that’s over $9 billion dollars in market cap.

So, while various pundits might claim that every CEO is replaceable, the question remains:  at what cost?  The answer isn’t found in the much vaunted proxy disclosures on executive compensation.

That $9 billion figure is a discounted future cash flow assessment of Mr. Hurd’s value.  In other words, in the apolitical judgment of equity investors, the only people with the incentive to make this collective judgment correctly, the company would have been better off paying about $2 billion a year for the next five or six years to keep Mr. Hurd than to lose him.

In fairness to the board, the Mr. Hurd they let go, the man who broke the HP ethics code he had done so much to champion, was not quite the Mr. Hurd the investors thought they had before the Friday announcement.  There was a legitimate concern that the expense-fudging Mr. Hurd could no longer govern with the same authority he had before this unfortunate news came out.  But that’s not the point here.

The point is that the buttoned-down guy atop his Silicon Valley perch that HP’s investors thought they had was worth far more than the mere tens of millions that the media (check out the comments) and good governance types have regularly derided.

Update:  Stephen Bainbridge weighs in.  Larry Ribstein offers his take.

How much severance will Mark Hurd get?

Posted by Marc Hodak on under Executive compensation, Reporting on pay | Be the First to Comment

The numbers in the papers:  $28 million to $40 million.

The right number:  $12.2 million

That is the amount he is entitled to under the company’s pre-negotiated “Severance Plan for Executive Officers of Hewlett-Packard Company.”  All the rest is money he has already earned, and doesn’t deserve to be called “severance.”  Severance is what a company pays someone to shut up and go away.  It’s not what someone has already earned but not yet taken out of the company, generally for tax reasons.  The media gets this wrong all the time.